Wednesday, 18 November 2015

John Plender, Capitalism


The capitalist system, which we live and breathe, rests on a remarkable logic: a group of selfish individuals, each one seeking  private happiness, produces a society where the greatest possible number get what they want – or something like it. Through the magic of the free market, Adam Smith’s too-oft-quoted ‘invisible hand’, selfishness actually produces its opposite, a functioning and prosperous society broadly advantageous to its members. Private acquisition agglomerates into public good; from competition comes community; greed spawns gregariousness, or at any rate its mercantile analogue. This central paradox, which has its origin in utilitarianism’s pursuit of the maximization of pleasure across society, is quite dizzying when you think about it. How can the pursuit of A, by the alchemy of the market, produce not-A? Yet this system, based on the private pursuit of capital and so known as capitalism, has achieved remarkable things. Over two centuries or so, it has raised the living standards of most of the world and dramatically reduced global poverty. The technology, medicine, comforts and luxuries many of us take for granted today would have seemed a miracle even a generation ago.  No other economic system is available as a credible alternative: feudalism has disappeared into history, leaving only a quaint residue such as the peerage system and the royal family; communist central planning collapsed dramatically (economically speaking: central planning in other areas, such as education, is pursued ardently across the bureaucratised West). Other than capitalism, what economic system is going to bring, say, a Bangladeshi or a Somalian the standard of living I enjoy – running water, hygiene, education, all the rest of it? If you agree that they are as entitled to these things as I am  (and what rational basis could there be for disagreement on this point?) what is there to do but to espouse the market as the most likely source of this development? Capitalism has triumphed over its rivals and has a long list of achievements to its credit.

Yet gung-ho, Gordon Gecko ‘Greed is Good’ celebrations of capitalism are rare these days; and Capitalism is presently assailed by many critics, from many shades of the political spectrum (only a very selective observer could say they are all ‘left wing’). For one thing, the fact that it is posited on human selfishness makes it ethically dubious, whatever the alleged long-term beneficial consequences of this greed may be. Moral intuition and religious systems alike persuade us that avarice is a vice, corrupting of the self and damaging to others. And the model of a rational consumer going into a free market , and thereby helping it to function efficiently for the good of the majority, exposes itself to critique at every point: are we really rational consumers? Do we not desire and buy things on a whim, yielding to the tide of fashion, or sometimes - perhaps regularly - in an act of madness?  And what does it do to us psychologically, ethically, to think of ourselves as essentially ‘consumers’ anyway? To make us into non-stop consumers, a massive advertising industry is necessary, playing on every conceivable fear, anxiety and fantasy to make us think that buying stuff will make us happy. And to make all that stuff that we are duped into thinking we need, the planet is steadily raided for its resources, polluted and spoiled. We are consuming the earth we live off; and if that sounds eco-hippy, then capitalism’s purchase of the channels of information in education and the media has been a success. And how free, we may then ask, is the alleged ‘free’ market, where government intervention and policy massively influences trade and production, favouring some in the market at the cost of others? How can we call it efficient, we may persist,  when it is so obviously inherently unstable, with a rollercoaster of booms, busts, frenzies, and recessions? And rather than the greatest good of the greatest number flowing from this market - a market so intrusive and ubiquitous we now carry it around with us on our phones - we see instead ever-widening gaps between the haves and the have-nots as goods are unevenly distributed, partly because the governments that might do something to distribute wealth more equitably are themselves owned by the rich who want to keep their treasure hoard to themselves. Consumerism, materialism, waste and pollution, injustice and inequality, the destruction of the planet and the trivialisation of the human spirit. Capitalism’s defenders face too many sane and sagacious critics to be blandly complacent.

John Plender, thankfully, is anything but complacent, and interested in serious debate. Capitalism leads us through the subject with great dexterity. As a writer for The Financial Times and a member of various financial groups and forums, Plender is what one might think of as a member of the establishment. Yet far from the closed-mindedness  one associates with this rather fictitious group, Plender shows common ground with many anti-establishment critics. He does not believe the mess of 2007-08 has been anywhere near cleared up through improvements in analysis, assumptions and regulation – indeed, he fears another and bigger crash is on the cards. He points out inequitable wage differentials, and notes the waste of human resources as the talented young are drawn into the financial sector and away from productive parts of the economy; and his brilliantly lucid analysis of the Eurozone crisis is pretty severe at the behaviour of the northern countries towards the south. In an interesting chapter on the art market, the author clearly feels commodification, the equation of financial value with other kinds of value, has to stop somewhere. Capitalism is not a defence of the status quo and makes clear that capitalism needs to get its house in much better order if further gains are to be delivered and catastrophe avoided. Like Erasmus on the Catholic Church, Plender believes the system needs to reform from within, not be dismantled and replaced with an unclear substitute.

An attractive feature of the book is the use of literary sources to investigate topics. It is refreshingly historically grounded. So we have passages of Defoe and Addison on the London Exchange, Goethe’s Faust as a commentary on externalities and social dysfunction, and apposite quotations from Dickens, de Tocqueville and many others besides. The author is open to the ideas of many different kinds of economist, too. Like Ha-Joon Chang, Plender thinks it is a pity that many economists today take the Chicago school as a comprehensive explanatory model and ignore other perspectives. Certainly some young students of economics I meet come across as acolytes of a faith rather than serious analysts of events. How satisfying it is to find here a range of writers being drawn on and engaged with: across pages 282-4, for example, we come across Marx, Keynes, Friedman and Raghuram Rajan in a discussion of public debt. Capitalism might perhaps have said something more about the psychology induced by capitalist ideology; and somewhat surprisingly there is no chapter specifically about environmental damage, which the author himself mentions as one of the greatest challenges to be faced. This is also not the book to read it you want to find out what ‘derivative’ or ‘futures market' means, since the author has to take some things for granted just to get going (that said, some terms are defined deftly along the way). However, no one book on this huge subject can do everything and the topics covered by these chapters, from the nature of money itself to debt, speculation, banking and gold are described with style and insight. I learned a lot from Capitalism and would certainly recommend it as a guide to a subject, and debate, which is far too important to be left to economists, establishment or otherwise.

No comments: